• ⚠️ UK Access Block Notice: Beginning July 1, 2025, this site will no longer be accessible from the United Kingdom. This is a voluntary decision made by the site's administrators. We were not forced or ordered to implement this block.

DarkRange55

DarkRange55

We are now gods but for the wisdom
Oct 15, 2023
2,016
Had to break into two sections because of word limit. If it's too long, then don't read. Used Chat to edit, sue me. Breaking some myths…

Section 2: Post-Revolutionary to Modern Era (Sections 8–23)


Part I, Section 8: The Constitutional Settlement on Money (1787–1790s)


The turmoil of the 1780s convinced many leaders that the Articles of Confederation lacked the authority to provide monetary stability. When delegates met in Philadelphia in 1787 to draft a new Constitution, questions of money, debt, and credit were central. Out of those debates came the Constitutional framework for U.S. money, the Coinage Act of 1792, and Alexander Hamilton's financial program, which together created a more durable foundation for the nation's economic life.





Monetary Provisions in the Constitution (1787)


The Constitution deliberately incorporated lessons from the collapse of the Continental and the chaos of state currencies: • Article I, Section 8 gave Congress the exclusive power to "coin money, regulate the value thereof, and of foreign coin, and fix the standard of weights and measures." • Article I, Section 10 prohibited states from coining money, emitting bills of credit, or making anything but gold and silver coin a legal tender in payment of debts.


These provisions stripped the states of monetary sovereignty, a direct response to the Rhode Island "paper money wars" and the inflation of the 1780s. Only the federal government could now issue coinage and regulate currency.


Notably, the Constitution did not explicitly authorize Congress to issue paper money. This ambiguity would later fuel controversies over greenbacks, banknotes, and "constitutional money."





The First U.S. Mint and the Coinage Act of 1792


To implement the new monetary framework, Congress passed the Coinage Act of 1792: • Established the U.S. Mint in Philadelphia, the nation's first federal mint. • Created the U.S. dollar as the unit of account, modeled directly on the Spanish milled dollar, which had been the most trusted coin in colonial circulation. • Defined the dollar in terms of both silver and gold, formally establishing a bimetallic standard: • $1 = 371.25 grains pure silver. • $10 "Eagle" = 247.5 grains pure gold (implying a 15:1 silver-to-gold ratio). • Authorized coinage of copper cents, silver dimes, quarters, half-dollars, and gold coins.


Although this Act established the U.S. dollar on firm statutory footing, in practice Spanish dollars and other foreign coins continued to circulate more widely than U.S. Mint issues, and they remained legal tender in the United States until 1857.





Hamilton's Financial Program


Alexander Hamilton, as the first Secretary of the Treasury (1789–95), saw monetary stability as essential to national power. His program, laid out in his Reports on Public Credit (1790–91) and Report on Manufactures (1791), had three pillars: 1. Funding the National Debt: • Hamilton proposed that the new federal government assume both federal and state Revolutionary War debts, consolidating them into one national obligation. • He insisted the debts be funded at full face value, even though much of it had been bought up by speculators at steep discounts. • This policy, though controversial, established U.S. creditworthiness. 2. Establishing a National Bank: • The First Bank of the United States (1791) provided a stable paper currency backed by specie reserves and gave the government a powerful fiscal agent. • The Bank could issue banknotes that circulated nationwide, helping unify the currency system. 3. Encouraging Manufacturing and Commerce: • Hamilton's Report on Manufactures (1791) advocated protective tariffs and subsidies to foster American industry. • Congress, however, never fully enacted this report. Its vision remained more a statement of policy direction than an immediate blueprint.





Immediate Impact • U.S. credit was restored in European markets, enabling the government to borrow at sustainable rates. • Specie coinage from the new mint began circulating, but in limited quantities; Spanish dollars continued to dominate everyday transactions well into the 19th century. • Banknotes of the First Bank spread widely, supplementing hard currency and helping to create a more uniform financial system.





Conclusion of Section 8


The Constitutional provisions, the Coinage Act of 1792, and Hamilton's financial program together created a durable framework for U.S. money. By anchoring the dollar in silver and gold, centralizing coinage under federal authority, and building institutions of credit, the new republic sought to ensure that it would never again suffer a collapse like the Continental dollar.


Yet, by leaving Congress's power to issue paper money ambiguous, the Constitution planted the seeds of future disputes. And while the Coinage Act aimed to define a uniquely American money, foreign silver coins — especially the Spanish dollar — remained more influential in daily commerce than U.S. coinage for decades.





Part I, Section 9: Early Challenges to the Monetary System (1790s–1830s)


The constitutional and legislative settlement of the 1790s gave the United States a stronger monetary framework than it had ever known. Yet it was not without controversy or early crises. The new system faced fierce political opposition, financial panics, and deep debates about the proper role of paper credit, banks, and government power in a republic.





Jefferson vs. Hamilton: The Bank Debate (1791)


When Alexander Hamilton proposed the First Bank of the United States in 1791, he envisioned it as a stabilizing force — an institution that could: • Hold federal revenues. • Issue uniform banknotes redeemable in specie. • Lend to the government and stimulate commerce.


But Thomas Jefferson and James Madison strongly opposed the Bank: • They argued the Constitution gave no explicit power to charter corporations. • Jefferson, in his famous opinion to Washington, declared that creating a bank was "not among the enumerated powers" and therefore unconstitutional. • Madison feared the Bank would favor wealthy creditors and entangle the young republic in "corrupt" financial practices reminiscent of Britain.


Hamilton countered with his "necessary and proper" argument: the Constitution empowered Congress to take implied measures to execute its fiscal responsibilities. Washington sided with Hamilton and signed the Bank bill in 1791.


This debate laid the foundation for America's first great constitutional argument over money and banking, a conflict that would recur throughout the 19th century.





The Panic of 1792


Barely a year into the new system, the United States experienced its first financial panic: • Fueled by speculation in U.S. government bonds and Bank of the U.S. stock, credit expanded rapidly in New York and Philadelphia. • When prices began collapsing in March 1792, panic spread. • Hamilton intervened decisively as Treasury Secretary: • The government purchased securities to stabilize prices. • He encouraged banks to extend credit to ease the crunch.


These were among the first examples of government market intervention to contain a financial panic. Hamilton's measures restored stability within weeks, but the episode showed how fragile the new credit system was.





The First Bank in Practice (1791–1811)


The First Bank of the United States functioned as a quasi-central bank, though not in the modern sense. It was privately owned but had a federal charter and performed key stabilizing roles: • Its banknotes became widely accepted, circulating nationally and supplementing specie. • By maintaining specie reserves, it restrained reckless over-issuance of notes by smaller state banks. • Critics accused it of favoring wealthy merchants and concentrating financial power in Philadelphia and New York.


When its charter came up for renewal in 1811, the Jeffersonian Republicans — now dominant — refused to renew it. The Bank closed after a narrow vote in Congress (House 65–64; Senate 17–19). Opposition was not just constitutional or ideological: geopolitical and populist concerns played a role, including distrust of concentrated financial power and fears over the Bank's foreign stockholders.





State Banks and the Early Monetary Patchwork


Even with the First Bank in place, dozens of state-chartered banks issued their own notes. These notes varied in reliability, and their acceptance often depended on geography and reputation. "Banknote reporters" and discount sheets circulated, listing the going market value (or discount) of different banks' notes in different cities.


This patchwork reflected the tension between Hamilton's desire for centralized stability and Jefferson's vision of local, state-based finance.





Conclusion of Section 9


The early republic's monetary system was a fragile balance between central authority and local experimentation. Hamilton's Bank and interventions during the Panic of 1792 showed the advantages of a strong federal role. Jeffersonian opposition underscored the fear that such institutions were undemocratic and unconstitutional.


The First Bank helped stabilize U.S. credit and created the first semblance of a national currency, but its demise in 1811 revealed how contested the very idea of centralized monetary authority remained. These early clashes set the stage for the later battles over the Second Bank of the United States, Andrew Jackson's "Bank War," and the continuing tension between hard money and paper credit in American political culture.





Part I, Section 10: The Second Bank of the United States and the Bank War (1816–1836)


The closure of the First Bank of the United States in 1811 left the young republic without a central stabilizing institution. The result was a surge in unregulated state banknote issuance and severe monetary instability during the War of 1812. Recognizing the chaos, Congress chartered a new national bank in 1816: the Second Bank of the United States (BUS). For twenty years it became both the anchor of U.S. credit and the target of the fiercest political struggle in early American monetary history — culminating in President Andrew Jackson's famous "Bank War."





Origins: War of 1812 and the Need for a Bank • With no national bank after 1811, the federal government struggled to finance the War of 1812. • State banks proliferated, issuing notes far beyond their specie reserves. Many suspended specie payments during the war. • Inflation and depreciation spread, and the Treasury had difficulty raising loans. • In response, Congress created the Second Bank of the United States in 1816 with a 20-year charter, capitalized at $35 million (far larger than the First Bank).


The charter allowed as much as 20% of its stock to be owned by foreigners, which later became one of the populist critiques of the Bank.





Early Problems and the Panic of 1819 • In its first years, the Second Bank was poorly managed under William Jones. It expanded credit recklessly, contributing to a speculative boom in land and commodities. • When the Bank sharply contracted credit in 1818–19 to restore specie discipline, the bubble burst. • The result was the Panic of 1819, America's first major peacetime financial crisis: • Land values collapsed, banks failed, unemployment rose. • Farmers and debtors blamed the BUS for foreclosures and tight credit.


This early mismanagement tarnished the Bank's reputation and fueled anti-bank sentiment, especially in the South and West.





Nicholas Biddle and Stabilization • In 1823, Nicholas Biddle became Bank president and restored discipline. • Under his leadership, the BUS functioned more effectively: • It regulated state banks by demanding specie redemption of their notes. • Its nationwide network of branches provided a relatively uniform paper currency. • It stabilized the nation's money supply by curbing reckless inflation.


By the late 1820s, many observers conceded that the Bank had become an essential stabilizing force in the financial system.





The Bank War: Jackson vs. Biddle • President Andrew Jackson, elected in 1828, distrusted the BUS. • He saw it as a "monster monopoly" that concentrated power in unelected hands, favored elites, and threatened republican liberty. • When the Bank's charter came up for renewal in 1832, Jackson vetoed it — one of the most famous veto messages in U.S. history. • He argued: • The Bank was unconstitutional (reviving Jefferson's old arguments). • It was politically corrupt, with foreign stockholders and special privileges. • It harmed "the humble members of society" while enriching the wealthy.


Congress failed to override his veto.





The "Removal of the Deposits" • In 1833, Jackson escalated by ordering federal deposits removed from the BUS and placed in selected "pet banks" (state banks). • This crippled the BUS's ability to regulate credit and marked the effective end of its central role, even though its charter technically continued until 1836. • Nicholas Biddle fought back by contracting credit to demonstrate the Bank's power, but this backfired, intensifying the public's hostility.





Aftermath • The BUS's federal charter expired in 1836; it briefly operated under a Pennsylvania state charter before collapsing in 1841. • Jackson's victory in the Bank War was a triumph for hard-money Democrats, who celebrated it as a defense of popular liberty. • But the destruction of the BUS left the United States with no central stabilizing institution. • The result was a period often called the "free banking" era: • Technically, the term refers to the wave of Free Banking Acts passed by states beginning in the 1830s–40s. • More broadly, historians use it to describe the post-BUS decades when state-chartered banks proliferated, paper notes were unstable, and credit cycles were frequent.





The National Debt Paid Off


One remarkable byproduct of Jackson's policies was that in 1835, under his administration, the United States paid off the entire national debt — the only time in its history. This was achieved by applying land sales and tariff revenues to debt retirement. While celebrated by Jacksonians, the achievement was temporary; the government soon fell back into debt during subsequent financial crises.





Conclusion of Section 10


The Second Bank of the United States embodied the paradox of early American finance. It was both the most effective stabilizer of the monetary system and the most politically controversial institution in the republic. Under Biddle it proved capable of restraining inflation and creating a uniform currency. But Jackson's populist attack, fueled by suspicion of concentrated financial power and foreign influence, destroyed it.


The Bank War (1832–1836) was more than a policy dispute: it was a defining struggle over the meaning of money, democracy, and economic power in America. The victory of Jacksonian hard-money populism ensured that the nation would stumble through decades of unstable banking and recurrent panics — setting the stage for new battles over currency in the mid-19th century.





Part I, Section 11: The Free Banking Era and Mid-19th Century Panics (1837–1860s)


With the demise of the Second Bank of the United States in 1836, the country entered a new chapter in its monetary history: the Free Banking Era. This period was marked by state-level control of banking, the proliferation of banknotes of widely varying quality, and repeated financial crises. It was a time of innovation but also instability, demonstrating both the opportunities and dangers of a fragmented banking system without a central anchor.





Jacksonian Hard Money and the Specie Circular • President Andrew Jackson and his supporters distrusted paper money and "corporate monopolies." They championed a hard money philosophy, preferring gold and silver coin as the foundation of the currency. • In 1836, Jackson issued the Specie Circular, requiring payment for federal land purchases in gold or silver rather than banknotes (with some exceptions for small settlers). • The intent was to curb rampant land speculation, which had been fueled by an explosion of state bank notes.


The Circular did not cause the coming crash by itself. But by draining specie out of banks at a moment when British lenders were already tightening global credit, it added to the financial fragility that set the stage for the Panic of 1837.





The Panic of 1837 • Triggered by a combination of speculative lending, falling cotton prices, and contraction of British credit, the U.S. economy collapsed in 1837. • Banks suspended specie payments nationwide, shattering public confidence in paper money. • Unemployment soared, bankruptcies spread, and hardship deepened. • A second downturn in 1839–1843 prolonged the depression, making this one of the most severe crises in early U.S. history.


The Panic of 1837 highlighted the dangers of a decentralized system of state banks issuing notes with inadequate specie backing.





The Free Banking Acts • Beginning in New York in 1838, states passed Free Banking laws that allowed anyone meeting set requirements (usually depositing state bonds as security) to open a bank and issue notes. • The reform was intended to democratize banking and reduce political favoritism in chartering.


In practice, results varied by state: • In New York and a few other states, free banking worked relatively well, producing reasonably stable institutions. • In the Midwest and frontier states, many "wildcat banks" emerged. These were often undercapitalized, located in remote areas, and issued notes that traded at deep discounts.


By the 1850s, thousands of different banknotes were circulating, each with its own discount depending on distance from the issuing bank and its perceived reliability.





The Panic of 1857 • Triggered by a global credit crunch, declining railroad securities, and a fall in grain exports, the Panic of 1857 struck both banks and industry. • Banks across the Midwest failed, and even New York's financial markets seized up. • The absence of a uniform, federally backed currency made recovery more difficult.


The Panic reinforced growing arguments that the U.S. needed a stronger national framework for banking and money.





Everyday Currency in the Free Banking Era • Americans dealt with a bewildering array of notes from state-chartered banks. • To navigate this system, merchants and travelers relied on banknote reporters and counterfeit detectors, which listed the discount or legitimacy of each note. • Counterfeiting was rampant — some estimates suggest that at certain points half of all notes in circulation were fake. • In rural areas, where paper was often distrusted, barter and commodity money (such as wheat, whiskey, or livestock) remained common in everyday exchange.





Conclusion of Section 11


The Free Banking Era was a laboratory of American finance: decentralized, entrepreneurial, and diverse — but also unstable and crisis-prone. Without a central regulator or uniform currency, the nation lurched from boom to bust, with frequent suspensions of specie payment and waves of bank failures.


The Free Banking Acts achieved their goal of reducing political favoritism in bank charters, but they also produced wildly uneven outcomes. In some regions they fostered stability; in others they gave rise to reckless "wildcat" institutions.


By the 1860s, as the Civil War loomed, it was clear that the U.S. needed a more unified banking and currency system. The pressures of war would provide the catalyst for the next transformation: the creation of the National Banking System and the first federally issued paper money, the greenbacks.





Part I, Section 12: The Civil War, Greenbacks, and the National Banking System (1861–1870s)


The outbreak of the Civil War in 1861 forced the United States into a monetary transformation as profound as the Revolution itself. The Union government, suddenly facing unprecedented wartime expenses, had to create a new system for raising revenue and managing money. Out of this crucible came the greenbacks — the first federally issued paper money not backed by specie — and the National Banking System, which restructured American finance for the remainder of the 19th century.





Wartime Finance and the Birth of Greenbacks • At the start of the war, the Union relied on customs duties, land sales, and borrowing. But expenses quickly exceeded revenues. • By late 1861, banks had suspended specie payments, making it impossible for the government to maintain gold convertibility. • In February 1862, Congress authorized the first issue of United States Notes ("greenbacks") under the Legal Tender Act.


Greenbacks were: • Declared legal tender for all debts, public and private (except customs duties and interest on federal debt, which still required gold). • Issued without direct backing in gold or silver. • Printed with green ink on the reverse, hence their enduring nickname.


Congress only passed the Legal Tender Act reluctantly, framing it as a wartime emergency measure. Many legislators believed making notes legal tender was unconstitutional in peacetime but justified by necessity. This marked a dramatic break from the hard-money tradition that had dominated U.S. finance since the founding.





Inflation and Market Reactions • Initially issued in small amounts ($150 million in 1862), greenbacks soon expanded to about $450 million by war's end. • Their value fluctuated against gold, traded on a "gold market" in New York. • At their worst point in July 1864, it took nearly $3 in greenbacks to buy $1 in gold. • Inflation hit around 80% over the course of the war — painful, but manageable compared with the hyperinflation of Confederate currency.





Constitutional Controversy: The Legal Tender Cases


The greenbacks revived the old constitutional question: could Congress issue paper money as legal tender? • Hepburn v. Griswold (1870): The Court, in a narrow 4–3 decision, held that Congress could not make greenbacks legal tender for debts contracted before the Legal Tender Act. Chief Justice Salmon P. Chase — ironically, Lincoln's Treasury Secretary who had overseen the greenbacks — wrote the opinion striking them down. • Knox v. Lee and Parker v. Davis (1871): Just one year later, with two new justices appointed by President Grant (William Strong and Joseph Bradley), the Court reversed itself in a 5–4 decision. The new majority upheld the constitutionality of greenbacks for both past and future debts, citing the federal government's broad monetary powers in emergencies. • Juilliard v. Greenman (1884): The Court went further, ruling that Congress's power to issue legal tender extended to peacetime as well. This decision cemented the doctrine that U.S. paper money was fully constitutional.


The abrupt shift from Hepburn (1870) to Knox/Parker (1871) illustrates how judicial personnel changes — not just legal reasoning — shaped constitutional outcomes.





The National Banking System (1863–64)


To organize wartime finance and create a uniform currency, Congress passed the National Banking Acts of 1863 and 1864: • Allowed nationally chartered banks to issue notes backed by holdings of U.S. government bonds. • Created the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency to supervise national banks. • Imposed a 10% tax on state banknotes in 1865, effectively driving them out of circulation.


It's important to note that national banknotes were not fiat in the same sense as greenbacks. They were directly backed by U.S. bonds deposited with the Treasury. This gave them credibility and, crucially, created a captive market for federal debt.


This system created, for the first time, a uniform national paper currency backed by federal credit and distributed through private national banks.





Everyday Currency in the Civil War Era • The North circulated a mix of greenbacks, gold coins (used mainly for customs and foreign trade), and national banknotes. • The South issued Confederate notes, backed only by a promise of future redemption. These depreciated disastrously, with inflation exceeding 9,000% by war's end. • Soldiers, farmers, and merchants in both regions had to adapt to rapid changes in money's value, often resorting to barter when paper became unreliable.





"In God We Trust" and Civil War Coinage


The Civil War era also left a cultural imprint on U.S. money. • In 1861, after receiving public petitions for religious expression on coins, Treasury Secretary Salmon P. Chase asked Mint Director James Pollock to prepare designs. • Congress authorized the change in 1864, and "In God We Trust" first appeared on the new two-cent piece. • Over time, the motto spread to other coinage (nickel in 1866, silver coins in the 1870s) and, much later, became standard on all U.S. money in the 20th century.


This marked the first moment where American money carried a religious motto, reflecting the era's wartime religiosity and the symbolic role of money as a bearer of national identity.





Conclusion of Section 12


The Civil War revolutionized American money. Greenbacks established the principle of fiat currency, while the National Banking System created the first nationwide uniform currency. Though inflationary and controversial, these measures allowed the Union to finance the war and emerge with a stronger, more centralized financial system.


But the legacy was double-edged: greenbacks sparked constitutional battles that lasted for decades, and the rigid bond-backed structure of the National Banking System created long-term credit bottlenecks. Still, by 1870 the United States had entered a new monetary era — one where paper money issued under federal authority was a permanent fixture of economic life.





Part I, Sections 13–14 & 16 (Merged): The Return to the Gold Standard (1870s–1900), the "Crime of 1873," the Silver Question, and Inflation and Deflation under the Gold and Silver Standards (19th Century Cycles)


The Civil War had broken decisively with America's monetary tradition. For the first time, the federal government issued large quantities of irredeemable paper money — greenbacks — which circulated alongside gold and silver coin. But the end of the war left unresolved a fundamental question: would the United States return to its constitutional foundation of metallic money, or would paper legal tender become permanent? The answer emerged over three turbulent decades, culminating in the U.S. commitment to the gold standard in 1900.


When currencies were tied to gold and silver, the money supply expanded only as fast as mines and mints could produce bullion. Unlike fiat systems, no central authority could simply create money in response to economic shocks. This meant that changes in global bullion output directly shaped inflation and deflation.


The nineteenth century was marked not just by battles over what counted as money — gold, silver, or paper — but also by wrenching changes in the purchasing power of money itself. The U.S. economy oscillated between episodes of inflation and long stretches of deflation, with each cycle shaping political movements, class relations, and the very meaning of democracy in finance.





Constitutional and Early Foundations • The U.S. Constitution, in Article I, Section 10, explicitly forbade states from making anything but gold and silver coin legal tender. While this clause applied only to states, it reflected the Founders' deep distrust of paper currency after the collapse of the Continental dollar. • The Coinage Act of 1792 codified this principle, establishing the U.S. dollar as 371.25 grains of pure silver, with gold coin also minted at a fixed 15:1 silver-to-gold ratio. This created a bimetallic standard, ensuring both gold and silver served as the nation's monetary anchors.


For most of the 19th century, this bimetallic framework — though often strained — remained central to Americans' conception of "constitutional money."


Early Bimetallic Stability and Strains (1790s–1850s) • With the Coinage Act of 1792, the young republic sought to guarantee stability through a bimetallic standard: both silver and gold were minted at fixed ratios and declared legal tender. The law defined the dollar as 371.25 grains of silver, with gold coins valued against silver at 15:1. • In practice, the fixed ratio often clashed with global market ratios. When silver was undervalued, it vanished from circulation; when gold was undervalued, it disappeared abroad. This instability was the classic operation of Gresham's Law ("bad money drives out good"). • In practice, silver dominated circulation because U.S. gold coins were undervalued at this ratio and often exported abroad. This amounted to what some historians call a de facto silver standard within the broader bimetallic framework. • As Mexico and other Latin American countries continued producing large volumes of silver, the global supply of silver remained relatively abundant through the mid-19th century. This kept U.S. coinage relatively plentiful. • Despite these strains, overall prices remained relatively stable. Inflation was limited by the natural scarcity of precious metals and the discipline of convertibility. • Exceptions occurred during wars: the War of 1812 triggered suspension of specie payments, leading to temporary inflation. Once specie redemption resumed in the 1820s, prices leveled again.





Civil War and the Inflation of Greenbacks (1861–1865) • The Union's resort to greenbacks was unprecedented: irredeemable paper legal tender that quickly became the everyday currency of the North. • Between 1861 and 1865, prices in the Union nearly doubled (roughly 75–80% cumulative inflation). Soldiers' wages and urban workers' pay often lagged, eroding living standards, while farmers with fixed mortgages or debts found repayment easier. • In the Confederacy, inflation reached catastrophic proportions. With little capacity to tax and limited access to specie, Richmond financed the war almost entirely with paper emissions. By 1865, Confederate money had depreciated to the point of near worthlessness, with cumulative inflation rates above 9,000%. • The contrast left a deep imprint: Union citizens viewed controlled fiat as a necessary evil, while Southerners remembered unbacked notes as synonymous with ruin.





The Postwar Dilemma: Greenbacks vs. Specie • After the Civil War, debate raged over whether to retire the greenbacks and resume specie payments. • "Hard money" advocates insisted that the U.S. must restore credibility by returning to a metallic standard, consistent with constitutional principles. • "Soft money" advocates — farmers and debtors especially — argued for keeping greenbacks in circulation, as they made credit easier and debts cheaper to repay.


This conflict echoed the deeper American tension between a creditor class favoring sound money and a debtor class favoring inflationary relief.





The Coinage Act of 1873 ("The Crime of 1873") • In 1873, Congress passed a new Coinage Act that, among other reforms, dropped the standard silver dollar from the list of authorized coins. • The Act did not outlaw silver altogether — smaller silver coins continued to circulate, and the U.S. Mint struck "trade dollars" for use in Asian commerce. But the omission of the traditional silver dollar meant that silver could no longer be coined freely at the Mint. • At the time, the decision attracted little notice — silver had been undervalued for decades, and few silver dollars circulated.


But in the mid-1870s, when massive new silver discoveries in the American West (notably Nevada's Comstock Lode) drove down silver's market value, the omission of silver coinage took on explosive significance. Farmers, miners, and debtors charged that a secret conspiracy of bankers and foreign interests had "betrayed" the bimetallic tradition established by the Constitution and the Coinage Act of 1792. They called it the "Crime of 1873."





The Resumption Act and the Gold Standard • In 1875, Congress passed the Specie Payment Resumption Act, which promised that, beginning Jan. 1, 1879, greenbacks would once again be redeemable in specie. • In practice, redemption was in gold only, since silver was no longer a full legal-tender option. • When the date arrived, the Treasury was prepared with ample gold reserves, and the public, reassured, presented relatively few greenbacks for redemption.


From 1879 onward, the U.S. was operating de facto on a gold standard, though without an explicit statutory declaration until 1900.





Deflation in the Resumption Era (1870s–1890s) • After the Civil War, policy turned toward restoring specie redemption. The Specie Resumption Act of 1875 set Jan. 1, 1879, as the date when greenbacks would again be redeemable, in practice in gold only. • From the Panic of 1873 through the mid-1890s, the U.S. endured a long period of deflation. Between 1873 and 1896, the general U.S. price level fell at an average rate of about 1.7% per year, cumulatively about 30%. • Economists sometimes label this the "Long Depression." Modern scholarship notes, however, that while prices fell persistently, output and real wages often grew. It was less a single continuous depression than a cycle of recessions, recoveries, and long-term deflation. • From the 1870s to the 1890s, gold production failed to keep pace with rapid industrial growth. The result was a long period of deflation, sometimes called the "Long Depression" (though modern historians stress it was a period of slow growth and falling prices, not continuous contraction). U.S. wholesale prices fell by nearly 30% between 1873 and 1896. • Farmers in particular were trapped in what they called the "deflationary squeeze." Grain, cotton, and livestock prices fell steadily, but debts contracted earlier had to be repaid in dollars worth more than when borrowed. Rural communities often blamed "the money power" — bankers, railroads, and creditors concentrated in the East. • Creditors, by contrast, saw falling prices as a sign of "sound money" discipline, proof that the dollar was strong and respected abroad. To them, deflation was the price of credibility.


Social Consequences of Deflation • Farmers: Falling crop prices devastated rural America. By the 1880s, many Midwestern and Southern farmers joined the Grange Movement and later the Populist Party, demanding monetary reform. • Workers: Deflation meant real wages could rise if pay held steady, but frequent recessions (1873, 1884, 1893) led to job losses. The unemployed and underpaid often saw the strong-dollar policy as benefiting elites. • Creditors vs. Debtors: Deflation redistributed wealth upward — creditors were repaid in dollars worth more, while debtors were crushed. This sharpened class antagonisms and regional divisions.





The Silver Question and Monetary Politics • The demonetization of silver in 1873 (the so-called Crime of 1873) amplified discontent. Free silver advocates argued that reintroducing unlimited silver coinage at a 16:1 ratio with gold would expand the money supply, generate mild inflation, and relieve the deflationary burden. • Silver coinage became a populist cause. Movements such as the Greenback Party (1870s) and the Populist Party (1890s) made inflationary money central to their platforms. • The climax came with William Jennings Bryan's 1896 "Cross of Gold" speech, where he denounced the gold standard as crucifying farmers and workers on a "cross of gold." His fiery rhetoric captured the desperation of those ruined by deflation. • The Silver Question and Populist Revolt: The demonetization of silver created one of the defining political and economic debates of the late 19th century: • Silver Advocates ("Silverites"): Farmers, miners, and populists demanded the "free coinage of silver" at a fixed ratio (often 16:1), believing it would expand the money supply, raise farm prices, and ease debt burdens. They argued that silver had been the constitutional money of the people since 1792, and its removal was a betrayal engineered by creditors. This hurt indebted farmers and workers, who had to repay debts in dollars that were becoming more valuable over time. The political backlash was fierce, culminating in the Populist "Free Silver" movement and William Jennings Bryan's 1896 "Cross of Gold" speech, which attacked the gold standard as a policy that crucified ordinary Americans on a "cross of gold." • Gold Advocates: Bankers, creditors, and urban elites insisted on sticking with gold to preserve international confidence, arguing that inflationary silver coinage would damage the economy and punish savers.


This conflict spilled into politics with intensity. The Greenback Party in the 1870s and the Populist Party in the 1890s both made "free silver" central demands, culminating in William Jennings Bryan's famous 1896 "Cross of Gold" speech: "You shall not crucify mankind upon a cross of gold."





Global Context: Other Nations Move to Gold


The American struggle was part of a broader global monetary shift: • Britain had long been on a de facto gold standard (since 1821). • Germany, flush with French indemnity payments after the Franco-Prussian War (1871), abandoned silver and adopted gold in 1873 — the same year as the U.S. Coinage Act. • The Latin Monetary Union (France, Italy, Belgium, Switzerland, later Greece) effectively suspended silver coinage in the 1870s, aligning more closely with gold. • Japan adopted a gold standard in 1897, modeling its system after Britain's.


Thus, when the U.S. shifted away from silver, it was not alone but part of a global trend toward gold as the universal monetary standard.


Global Pressures and the Deflationary Bias of Gold • The U.S. deflation was part of a wider global trend. Germany's adoption of the gold standard in 1871–73, followed by the Latin Monetary Union's retreat from silver and Japan's adoption of gold in 1897, meant the world's demand for gold increased. • With limited new discoveries, the supply of gold grew slowly relative to industrial economies, producing a global deflationary tendency. • The U.S. could not escape this international constraint: aligning with the gold standard meant importing the world's shortage of monetary metal. • By the 1870s–1900s, most major economies (Britain, Germany, France, Japan, and eventually the U.S.) had adopted the gold standard. This global system created exchange-rate stability but made all countries vulnerable to the supply limits of gold mining. Periods of slow gold output translated into global deflation. Periods of discovery brought mild inflation. The standard thus hard-wired boom-and-bust pressures into the price level.





The gold discoveries and the return of inflation


Deflationary pressure eased after major new gold discoveries in South Africa (Witwatersrand, 1886 onward), the Klondike and Yukon (1896), and Alaska (Nome, 1899). Gold output surged, nearly tripling global supply by the early 20th century. This influx expanded the money base, restoring mild inflation and easing debt burdens.


Relief Through Gold Discoveries (1890s) • Salvation came not from policy but from geology. The Witwatersrand discoveries in South Africa (1886 onward), along with the Klondike and Yukon gold rushes of the late 1890s, unleashed an unprecedented flood of new gold into the world economy. • This surge finally ended the deflationary spiral. After 1896, U.S. prices began to rise moderately, easing the burden on debtors and farmers. • With deflation relieved, political energy drained from the free silver cause. By 1900, the Gold Standard Act codified what was already de facto reality.





The Gold Standard Act of 1900


After decades of agitation, the issue was settled by the Gold Standard Act of 1900, which declared gold the sole standard of value for the U.S. dollar. Silver remained in circulation as subsidiary coinage, but it was no longer a monetary anchor.


This marked the formal end of America's bimetallic heritage and the constitutional vision of money as both silver and gold coin.


The Gold Standard Act of 1900 formally placed the United States on the gold standard alone, ending bimetallism in law as well as practice. From this point until World War I, U.S. currency was legally tied only to gold.





World War I, interwar instability, and the Great Depression


Most countries suspended the gold standard during World War I to finance war spending. Britain attempted to return to gold in 1925 at the pre-war parity but had to abandon it again in 1931 under speculative pressure. The U.S. maintained gold convertibility longer, but President Roosevelt suspended domestic redemption in 1933.


Economists have since argued that this rigidity made the Great Depression worse. Ben Bernanke (2000) and Barry Eichengreen (1992) showed that countries which clung longest to gold suffered the deepest contractions because they could not expand their money supplies. In Bernanke's words, "the gold standard transmitted deflationary impulses" across borders and amplified the Depression's severity.





Conclusion of Merged Sections 13–14 & 16


The post–Civil War decades saw the United States wrestle with the meaning of money itself. The Constitution and the Coinage Act of 1792 had enshrined gold and silver as the nation's foundation. The Civil War broke that tradition with greenbacks. And the Coinage Act of 1873, the "Crime of 1873," completed the shift to gold alone.


For hard money advocates, this restored U.S. credit and placed the nation firmly in line with Britain and other global powers. For silver advocates and populists, it was a historic betrayal of the people's money, deepening rural hardship and widening the gap between debtor and creditor.


The battle over gold versus silver revealed that money was never just a neutral medium — it was a political weapon, a constitutional question, and a cultural symbol of who controlled the American economy.


Inflation and deflation under the 19th-century metallic standards were not technical curiosities but daily realities that reshaped American society. Inflation during the Civil War had been painful but manageable, easing debts while burdening workers. Deflation during the Resumption Era was far more corrosive: it hardened class divisions, radicalized farmers, and sparked new political movements.


Ultimately, it was the natural discovery of gold deposits, not the success of any political platform, that broke the cycle. This outcome underscored the vulnerability of a money supply tied to the vagaries of mining, geology, and global flows of bullion. The struggles of this era set the stage for the great 20th-century debates over whether the gold standard was a blessing or a curse — and whether money should be bound to metal at all.


Bottom line • The U.S. began with a bimetallic system, but silver dominated until the "Crime of 1873" ended free coinage. • The 1870s–1890s saw prolonged deflation as gold supply lagged growth, sparking populist unrest. • Gold discoveries in the 1890s restored moderate inflation and monetary expansion. • The Gold Standard Act of 1900 entrenched gold as the sole anchor. • Globally, the gold standard produced stability in exchange rates but instability in prices. • In the 1930s, the gold standard's deflationary bias contributed directly to the depth of the Great Depression, leading to its abandonment.





Part I, Section 15: International Gold Accumulation and U.S. Reserves (World War I to World War II)





Pre–World War I: London as the Financial Center


At the dawn of the 20th century, the City of London was the heart of the global financial system. Sterling, not the dollar, was the world's reserve currency, supported by Britain's empire, global trade networks, and the Bank of England's credibility. Gold flowed through London clearinghouses, and international trade typically settled on a sterling–gold basis. The U.S., though growing rapidly as an industrial power, was still financially subordinate. Wall Street and the newly created Federal Reserve (1913) were minor players compared to London.





World War I and the Shift of Gold to the U.S. (1914–1918)


When war erupted in 1914, European nations suspended gold convertibility to conserve reserves for military finance. The United States, neutral until 1917, became the supplier of food, arms, and raw materials. Gold poured into American banks and Treasury accounts as Europe paid for imports. By 1917, the U.S. had surpassed all others as the largest single holder of monetary gold. This was the moment the U.S. began shifting from debtor to global creditor, while Europe drained its gold stocks.





The 1920s: America as Creditor Nation


After the war, the U.S. emerged as the world's dominant creditor. European allies owed Washington billions in war debts; Germany owed reparations. Gold inflows continued through the 1920s, reinforcing America's new position.


But imbalances brewed: • In 1925, Winston Churchill restored sterling to its prewar parity of $4.86/£1. This move, hailed as patriotic, was disastrous: the pound was overvalued by 10–15%, crippling exports and raising unemployment. Keynes warned in The Economic Consequences of Mr. Churchill (1925) that this policy would be deflationary and harmful. • The U.S. Federal Reserve's policies aggravated instability: low interest rates in the early 1920s financed loans abroad, but tightening in 1928–29 sucked gold back into New York, destabilizing European balances. • By the end of the decade, the U.S. held disproportionate reserves, leaving weaker countries vulnerable.





The Great Depression and Gold Strain (1929–1933)


The 1929 crash spread worldwide. Bound by gold-standard rules, central banks defended parity by raising interest rates, worsening deflation. • In the U.S., prices fell by 25% between 1929 and 1933, and unemployment soared over 20%. • Banks failed, and citizens hoarded gold coins. • Europe suffered cascading failures — Austria's Credit-Anstalt collapsed in 1931, triggering panic. Foreign holders demanded U.S. gold, further straining reserves.


Gold, meant to symbolize stability, had become a deflationary trap.





Roosevelt's Gold Revolution (1933–1934)


Franklin Roosevelt abandoned the old rules: • March 1933: Declared a national bank holiday. • April 1933: Issued Executive Order 6102, requiring Americans to surrender nearly all gold coin, bullion, and certificates by May 1. Penalties: $10,000 fine or 10 years' prison. • Gold Reserve Act of 1934: Transferred ownership of all Federal Reserve gold to the Treasury, revalued gold from $20.67 to $35/oz, devaluing the dollar ~40%. Treasury booked large "profits," used to create the Exchange Stabilization Fund.


This act consolidated U.S. gold power: the Treasury now held all bullion; the Fed only held certificates.





Fort Knox and the Gold Fortress (1936–1937)


With inflows mounting, a secure vault was built: • The U.S. Bullion Depository at Fort Knox, Kentucky, was completed in December 1936. • First shipments in January 1937 traveled under U.S. Army guard. • Fort Knox became both a fortress of bullion and a national symbol of financial supremacy.





Domestic Reactions and Legal Challenges


Americans complied but resented surrendering coins like the Double Eagle. Critics decried confiscation as unconstitutional. The Gold Clause Cases (1935) upheld Roosevelt's program 5–4, ruling Congress could nullify contracts requiring gold. Supporters credited devaluation with stabilizing farm prices and reviving confidence.





Why Foreign Gold Flowed into the U.S. (1930s–1940s)


U.S. dominance wasn't just from domestic changes but also international inflows: 1. European Instability: Fascism and war fears led France, Belgium, and the Netherlands to ship gold to New York and Fort Knox. 2. Britain Off Gold (1931): Investors fled sterling and sought dollars, still convertible to gold. 3. Roosevelt's $35 Price: Attracted gold sales worldwide; U.S. trade surpluses were settled in bullion. 4. World War II: Central banks from occupied Europe evacuated gold to America. Britain used gold shipments to pay for Lend-Lease war supplies. 5. Dollar Credibility: Despite banning domestic ownership, the U.S. kept convertibility abroad, cementing trust.





Britain Leaves Gold (1931) — Expanded


Britain's suspension in September 1931 was pivotal: • Wrong Parity (1925): Churchill's restoration of the prewar gold parity ($4.86/£1) overvalued sterling 10–15%. Exports collapsed, unemployment soared. Keynes predicted the damage. • Depression Shock: By 1931, unemployment reached 20%. Global trade collapsed; Britain ran deficits. • Speculative Attacks: Investors doubted the peg; gold drained from the Bank of England. • Invergordon Mutiny (Sept. 15–16, 1931): Naval pay-cut protests rocked confidence; markets panicked. • September 20, 1931: Convertibility suspended; sterling fell ~25%. Exports recovered, but the interwar gold system cracked. • Aftermath: Britain led the "sterling bloc." Scandinavia, Japan, and Commonwealth states followed. France and the "gold bloc" clung on until 1936.


This collapse marked the end of London's uncontested monetary leadership and foreshadowed U.S. supremacy.





By World War II: America as the World's Gold Hoarder


By 1940–41, the U.S. held well over half — often cited as nearly two-thirds — of world monetary gold. • Fort Knox, West Point, and Denver brimmed with bullion. • U.S. power rested not only on its industrial might but also its gold fortress. • This gave Washington leverage to design Bretton Woods (1944), anchoring the dollar to gold and the world to the dollar.





Part I, Section 17 — Post–Bretton Woods Era (1971–Present)


Nixon Ends Convertibility: The Gold Window Closes (1971)


By the late 1960s, the Bretton Woods system was cracking. The U.S. dollar was fixed at $35 per ounce of gold, and foreign central banks could redeem dollars for gold held at the U.S. Treasury. This worked in the 1940s–1950s, when the U.S. possessed nearly 70% of the world's official gold reserves (over 20,000 metric tons).


But by the 1960s, U.S. balance-of-payments deficits ballooned from overseas military spending on the Vietnam War, domestic outlays for the Great Society, and the rapid spread of dollar liabilities abroad (the "Eurodollar overhang"). At the same time, European economies were booming. Surplus countries like France and West Germany doubted Washington's ability to keep redeeming dollars at $35.


President Charles de Gaulle of France denounced America's "exorbitant privilege" in 1965, openly calling for a return to gold. France and others demanded bullion shipments in exchange for dollars. U.S. gold reserves fell below 9,000 tons by 1971. To defend the peg, the U.S. and allied central banks ran the London Gold Pool (1961–1968), intervening to hold the market price at $35. But speculative demand overwhelmed them, and the Pool collapsed in March 1968, forcing creation of a two-tier system (official vs. free-market gold prices).


By 1971, pressure was unbearable. West Germany and Switzerland abandoned dollar parity and revalued their currencies. Dollars abroad far exceeded U.S. gold stocks.


On 15 August 1971, President Richard Nixon went on national television and announced a dramatic package: • Suspension of dollar-gold convertibility ("closing the gold window"), ending the $35 peg. • A 90-day wage and price freeze, aimed at curbing inflation. • A 10% import surcharge, to push other nations to revalue their currencies.


This "Nixon Shock" effectively ended Bretton Woods. Though Nixon called the measure temporary, convertibility never resumed.


In December 1971, the Smithsonian Agreement attempted a patch: the dollar was devalued to $38/oz, and currency fluctuation bands widened. But speculative pressures returned, and by March 1973 most major currencies were floating freely. The Nixon Shock was thus the turning point: the U.S. dollar shifted from being "as good as gold" to a fiat currency backed only by government credibility.





Jamaica Accords and the IMF Second Amendment (1976–1978)


Nixon's suspension was unilateral; the international system caught up later. At a 1976 meeting in Kingston, Jamaica, the IMF's Interim Committee agreed on changes to its charter. The Second Amendment to the IMF Articles of Agreement took effect on 1 April 1978.


The reforms: • Abolished the official price of gold and IMF members' obligation to maintain parities. • Legalized floating exchange rates. • Barred the IMF from fixing gold's price or using it to value the SDR. • Authorized sales of ~50 million ounces of IMF gold: half restituted to members, half sold for development.


This was the formal international burial of Bretton Woods. Gold was "demonetized" in the IMF framework, even as nations continued to hold it as reserves.





Legalization of Private U.S. Gold Ownership (1974)


Domestically, Americans had been forbidden to own monetary gold since Executive Order 6102 (1933). That ban was repealed when Public Law 93-373 was signed in August 1974, effective December 31, 1974. Coinciding with legalization, U.S. exchanges launched COMEX gold futures on the same day, creating the foundation of modern gold derivatives.





Gold Price Liberalization and 1970s Inflation


With the peg gone, gold's price floated — and exploded. The 1970s brought oil shocks, stagflation, and dollar weakness. Investors piled into bullion, sending gold from $35 in 1971 to over $850/oz in January 1980 (roughly $3,000+ today). Gold's surge cemented its status as a hedge against inflation and political instability.





Volcker, Disinflation, and the Bear Market (1980s–1990s)


The rally ended when Federal Reserve chair Paul Volcker hiked interest rates above 19% in the early 1980s to crush inflation. Gold fell back toward $300–400, where it languished through the 1980s and 1990s.


During this period, many central banks judged gold obsolete and sold reserves. To prevent chaos, European banks signed the Central Bank Gold Agreements (CBGA, from 1999), capping coordinated sales. The UK's sale of 395 tons (1999–2002) at near-record lows, later dubbed "Brown's Bottom," became infamous.





Gold's Revival (2000s–2020s)


From 2000 onward, gold revived, driven by the dot-com crash, 9/11, Iraq War, 2008 financial crisis, and Eurozone debt crisis. Prices peaked near $1,920/oz in 2011, then surged again in the 2020s during inflation and geopolitical turmoil. By 2024–2025, gold set fresh records above $2,300/oz.





Bottom Line • The Nixon Shock (1971) ended convertibility, triggered the move to fiat dollars, and ushered in floating exchange rates. • The Jamaica Accords (1976–78) legally codified gold's "demonetization" in the IMF system. • U.S. citizens regained the right to own gold in 1974, and COMEX futures began the same day. • Gold spiked in the 1970s, collapsed in the 1980s–90s, then rebounded strongly in the 2000s–2020s. • Today, gold is no longer money but remains a reserve hedge and crisis asset.





Part I, Section 18 — Price Manipulation, Fixing, and Market Trust Issues


The credibility of modern gold pricing has hinged on two key venues: London's daily benchmark fixing (1919–2015, replaced by the LBMA Gold Price) and New York's COMEX futures (since 1974). Both were created to bring stability and transparency to bullion markets—but both later faced manipulation scandals that strained trust.


The London Gold Fixing (1919–2015): origins, abuse, and reform


The London Gold Fixing was inaugurated on 12 September 1919 by N. M. Rothschild & Sons with five bullion houses (Rothschild; Mocatta & Goldsmid; Pixley & Abell; Samuel Montagu; Sharps & Wilkins). The goal was to produce a single, authoritative twice-daily benchmark so miners, refiners, manufacturers, and official institutions could settle contracts and value reserves consistently—especially as London remained the world's bullion hub after World War I.


Over time, structural weaknesses emerged. A small group of banks set the price behind closed doors, and participants also traded around the benchmark—classic conflicts of interest. Academic work in the 2000s–2010s documented statistical anomalies around the fixing window consistent with manipulation. In May 2014, the UK FCA fined Barclays £26 million for failings that enabled manipulation of the afternoon fix. In 2016, Deutsche Bank settled U.S. civil benchmark-manipulation claims and turned over trader chats evidencing collusion. Other banks—HSBC, UBS, Société Générale, Bank of Nova Scotia—were named in related suits or investigations, and several ultimately settled portions of those claims.


The legacy Fix ceased on 19 March 2015 and was replaced on 20 March 2015 by the LBMA Gold Price, an electronic auction administered by ICE Benchmark Administration with expanded participation and regulatory oversight—an attempt to rebuild credibility after a century of opaque practice.


COMEX futures and the spoofing crackdown


After the U.S. restored private bullion ownership on 31 December 1974, COMEX launched standardized 100-troy-ounce gold futures the same day, creating the deepest venue for "paper gold." With depth came abuse—especially spoofing (placing/canceling large orders to mislead prices), outlawed explicitly under Dodd-Frank (2010).


From 2018–2020, U.S. regulators announced a wave of penalties: UBS ($15m, 2018), HSBC ($1.6m, 2018), Deutsche Bank ($30m, 2018), Scotiabank ($77.4m, 2020, plus a DOJ resolution), and—most prominently—JPMorgan Chase ($920m, 2020; DOJ/CFTC/SEC combined), with DOJ describing a "massive, multi-year scheme" (2008–2016). Several individual traders (including former JPMorgan and Credit Suisse personnel) were criminally convicted. Collectively, these actions established that misconduct in U.S. precious-metals futures was systemic across multiple desks and firms.


Other precious-metals benchmarks (PGMs)


Benchmark vulnerability extended beyond gold. In litigation over platinum and palladium benchmarks, Goldman Sachs, BASF, HSBC, and ICBC Standard reached a $20 million settlement preliminarily in 2024; final approval was granted 22 January 2025. While this case concerned PGMs, not gold, it reinforced that benchmark-setting across the precious-metals complex faced similar risks.


The "paper gold" structure and persistent mistrust


A structural concern remains: open interest in COMEX gold futures often dwarfs deliverable stocks in exchange vaults. Critics say this enables "naked shorting" and artificial price suppression. Exchanges and banks counter that futures are primarily for hedging/speculation, most contracts never deliver, and surveillance/margin regimes are robust. Regulators have confirmed widespread spoofing but not a coordinated, systemic price-suppression policy. Still, the gap between paper volumes and physical stocks—and the enforcement record—keeps mistrust alive among many gold holders.


Bottom line • The London Fix solved a post-WWI need for a common benchmark but proved abusable, prompting its replacement by the LBMA Gold Price in 2015. • COMEX became the world's dominant gold venue but saw repeated spoofing scandals; penalties culminated in JPMorgan's $920m resolution, with multiple traders convicted. • Goldman Sachs and others settled over PGM benchmark claims, underscoring broader precious-metals benchmark risks. • The scale of derivatives vs. physical continues to fuel skepticism that quoted prices always reflect real-world bullion supply and demand.





Part I, Section 19 — Basel Banking Rules and Gold's Prudential Treatment


Origins of Basel Rules


The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) was established in 1974, after the collapse of Bankhaus Herstatt in West Germany disrupted cross-border currency settlements. The Committee's goal was to create common regulatory standards for internationally active banks. Its successive frameworks — Basel I (1988), Basel II (2004), and Basel III (2010s) — focus on capital adequacy, liquidity, and funding stability.


These rules apply to commercial banks, not central banks. The Federal Reserve, ECB, Bank of England, and other central banks help set Basel standards and enforce them on their commercial banking sectors, but they are not bound by the requirements themselves.





Gold under Basel I and II • Basel I (1988): Gold was assigned a 50% risk weight for credit-risk purposes — much less favorable than cash or sovereign bonds (0%). This meant banks had to hold more capital against gold holdings. • Basel II (2004): Gold remained classified as a "commodity," subject to market-risk capital charges. It was not treated as cash or sovereign bonds and did not qualify as High-Quality Liquid Assets (HQLA).





Basel III Reforms (Post-2008 Crisis)


The 2008 Global Financial Crisis exposed liquidity and funding weaknesses. Basel III introduced two new standards: • Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR): requires banks to hold HQLA (cash, central bank reserves, highly rated sovereign bonds) sufficient to cover 30 days of outflows under stress. Gold is not HQLA. • Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR): requires long-term stable funding for illiquid assets. Gold holdings — both allocated and unallocated — receive an 85% Required Stable Funding (RSF) factor, meaning banks must fund nearly the full value of gold with equity or long-term liabilities.


By contrast, sovereign bonds typically carry 0–5% RSF, making them far cheaper to hold than gold. This tilts bank balance sheets toward government debt and away from gold.





The Myth of "Tier 1 Gold"


A widespread claim in industry blogs is that Basel III made gold "a Tier 1 asset, like cash or Treasuries." This is incorrect. • Tier 1 capital = common equity and retained earnings, not gold. • Gold does not qualify as HQLA under the LCR. • Gold's 85% RSF under the NSFR makes it more expensive to hold than sovereign bonds, which carry close to 0% RSF.


The confusion arose because Basel III allowed allocated physical gold to be recognized on balance sheets at full market value (rather than discounted, as under Basel II). But this was a technical clarification, not an upgrade to Tier 1 status.





Why It Matters • For commercial banks: Basel III rules discourage large gold positions. Banks prefer government bonds, which are cheaper to hold under liquidity and funding requirements. • For central banks (including the Federal Reserve): Basel rules do not apply. Central banks can (and do) hold gold as part of their reserves without Basel constraints. • For markets: Basel III reinforced that gold is a recognized financial asset but not equivalent to cash or sovereign debt in banking regulation.





Bottom Line • Basel I & II: Gold treated as a risk-weighted commodity (50%), not cash. • Basel III: • Gold is not HQLA under the LCR. • Gold carries an 85% RSF under the NSFR, compared with 0–5% for sovereign bonds. • Basel rules apply to commercial banks, not central banks. The Fed enforces Basel on U.S. banks but does not apply it to its own reserves. • Result: gold is more expensive for banks to hold than bonds, but central banks remain free to accumulate it.





Part I, Section 20 — Central-bank gold buying & selling in modern times


From European sales to net buying


For much of the late 20th century, central banks in advanced economies were net sellers of gold. Under the Central Bank Gold Agreements (CBGA, 1999–2019), European banks coordinated sales to avoid disrupting the market, capping disposals at 400–500 tonnes per year. The UK famously sold 395 t between 1999 and 2002 ("Brown's Bottom"), while Switzerland, the Netherlands, and France also reduced stocks. By the 2010s, however, sales had dwindled, and the CBGA was allowed to expire in 2019. Since then, official-sector behavior has reversed: central banks have been net buyers for 15 consecutive years, with record additions of ~1,000 tonnes annually in 2022, 2023, and 2024.





The big buyers of the 2020s • China (PBoC): Officially reports ~2,264 t as of mid-2025, but analysts argue it likely holds more through state banks and SAFE. China's reporting is opaque: long pauses (2009, 2015, 2019) followed by sudden jumps (e.g., Nov 2022, late 2024). Motives: diversification away from U.S. Treasuries, sanctions resilience, and strategic hedging. • Russia (Bank of Russia): Holds ~2,330 t. Large-scale buying began after 2014 Crimea sanctions; slowed in 2020–21; surged again after Feb 2022, when ~$300B of FX reserves were frozen. Russia now treats gold as a core "sanctions-proof" reserve. • Turkey: A volatile player. It was the largest buyer in 2022, then a seller in early 2023 (to relieve local shortages during a currency crisis), but resumed net buying in 2024–25. • India (RBI): By March 2025, holdings stood at ~880 t (+57 t y/y). India steadily raises gold's reserve share and occasionally repatriates foreign-stored bars. • Poland (NBP): Among Europe's most aggressive buyers. As of June 2025, holdings reached ~515 t, surpassing the ECB's ~506.5 t. NBP Governor Adam Glapiński has targeted 20% of reserves in gold. • Hungary (MNB): Boosted gold from 3.1 t (2018) → 31.5 t → 94.5 t (2019) → ~110 t (2024). No new buys since 2021, but Hungary remains notable among European peers. • Kazakhstan & Uzbekistan: Swing buyers/sellers as they absorb domestic mine output. Kazakhstan was a net seller in 2023 but resumed buying in 2025 (+15 t YTD to ~299 t). Uzbekistan follows similar cycles. • Other buyers: • Singapore (MAS): +77 t in 2021–22. • Czech National Bank: steady additions since 2022, aiming for 100 t by 2028 (already ~50 t by 2025). • Middle East: Qatar, Iraq, Jordan, UAE have all added modestly in recent years.





The non-buyers (steady holders) • United States: 8,133 t (unchanged since the 1970s). Largest holder. • Germany: 3,355 t; repatriated 674 t from New York/Paris (2013–2017), no net new buying. • Italy: 2,452 t, stable. • France: 2,436 t, stable. • Japan (BoJ): 765 t, unchanged in decades. • United Kingdom: 310 t, steady since post-2002. • Mexico: 120 t, mainly from a 2011 purchase. • Brazil: 130 t, after a 2021 addition, stable in 2024–25. • Cambodia: ~13 t, unchanged.





The outlier seller • Canada: Sold nearly all reserves by 2016, leaving <0.1 t. It is the only G7 nation without meaningful gold holdings.





IMF's role


The 1976 Jamaica amendments ended the official gold price and "demonetized" gold in the IMF system. In 2009–2010, the IMF sold 403 t, including 200 t to India; the rest went to Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, Mauritius, and market sales.





Is this really "de-dollarization"?


Gold buying is often labeled de-dollarization, but the evidence is mixed: • Yes: For Russia, China, Turkey, and other sanction-exposed states, gold reduces dollar reliance and shields reserves from freezes. • No: The U.S. dollar still makes up 58–60% of FX reserves and over 80% of trade invoicing. Gold is a hedge and diversification tool, not a replacement.


The better term is reserve diversification — gold supplements the dollar rather than displacing it.





Bottom line • Past: Europe (1999–2010) was the main seller; CBGA capped and coordinated disposals. • Present: Since 2010, central banks are consistent net buyers, led by emerging markets. • Biggest buyers: China, Russia, Turkey, India, Poland, Hungary, Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, Singapore, Middle Eastern banks. • Non-buyers: U.S., Germany, Italy, France, UK, Japan, Mexico, Brazil, Cambodia. • Seller: Canada (virtually none left). • Gold accumulation reflects inflation hedging, sanctions resilience, and portfolio diversification — less a revolt against the dollar than a global insurance policy.





Part I, Section 21 — Gold as Tradition, Culture, and Habit in Central Banking





21a. Germany and the Bundesbank: Gold as "Trust Anchor"


Germany's Bundesbank provides one of the clearest examples of gold's symbolic weight. After the hyperinflation of 1921–23 and the collapse of the Reichsmark, Germans developed lasting skepticism toward paper currency. When the Bundesbank was created in 1957, it inherited this cultural memory.


Today, Germany holds 3,355 tonnes, the world's second-largest official stock after the U.S. The Bundesbank has repeatedly described its reserves as an "anchor of trust" and "bedrock of stability." In practice, gold is not about daily liquidity but about confidence in the institution itself.


This explains why, between 2013 and 2017, the Bundesbank repatriated 674 tonnes of gold from New York (300 t) and Paris (374 t) back to Frankfurt. Officially, the motive was to increase transparency and sovereignty, but the move also reflected widespread public debate and pressure inside Germany to "bring the gold home."


📚 Deutsche Bundesbank, Repatriation of Germany's Gold Reserves Completed (2017).





21b. India: Cultural Wealth and Official Strategy


India combines official reserves with an immense cultural affinity for gold. The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) holds ~880 tonnes officially, but Indian households are estimated to hold over 20,000 tonnes — the largest private stockpile in the world. These estimates vary, but the scale is undisputed. Gold plays a central role in weddings, dowries, and religious festivals such as Diwali and Akshaya Tritiya.


This cultural backdrop shapes the RBI's gold policy. In 2009, India bought 200 tonnes directly from the IMF during its gold sales, a move celebrated domestically as asserting economic sovereignty. By March 2025, RBI holdings stood near 880 t, and India has also repatriated some bars stored abroad. For India, gold is both a reserve hedge and a politically symbolic asset tied to national identity.


📚 World Gold Council, India Gold Market series; IMF 2009 gold sales reports.





21c. China: Secrecy and Strategic Accumulation


China's gold strategy blends official secrecy with cultural tradition. Officially, the People's Bank of China reports ~2,264 tonnes as of mid-2025. But China's reporting is irregular: it may remain silent for years (2009, 2015, 2019) and then suddenly disclose large additions (e.g., +604 t in 2015, steady monthly additions 2022–24).


Most analysts believe China holds more than reported, as accumulation is often channeled through the State Administration of Foreign Exchange (SAFE) and state-owned banks. This opacity allows Beijing to diversify quietly away from U.S. Treasuries while avoiding market shock or political signaling.


At the same time, Chinese households are heavy buyers of jewelry and investment bars, making China one of the largest physical gold consumers globally. Thus, China's official strategy mirrors its cultural foundation: gold as a hedge against both inflation and geopolitical risk.


📚 Reuters, WGC Gold Demand Trends (2024–25); IMF IFS; PBoC disclosures.





21d. The IMF: Demonization without Abandonment


The International Monetary Fund illustrates gold's paradox. The 1976 Jamaica Amendments to its Articles of Agreement abolished the official gold price, ended the par value system, and formally "demonetized" gold by prohibiting its use in exchange-rate definitions.


Yet, the IMF still holds ~2,814 tonnes (90.5 million ounces), making it the third-largest official holder after the U.S. and Germany. The Fund describes gold as an "important financial buffer" for crisis stability, even though it no longer plays a formal monetary role.


The IMF's 2009–2010 sales (403 t, including 200 t to India and the remainder to Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, Mauritius, and markets) confirmed that member states still valued gold as part of reserve diversification. The paradox is clear: gold was stripped of its official legal role in 1976, yet remains indispensable at the heart of the IMF's balance sheet.


📚 IMF, Articles of Agreement, Second Amendment (1976); IMF "Gold in the IMF" (2024).





Bottom Line of Section 21


Gold persists in central banks not because of law but because of tradition, culture, and politics. • In Germany, it is about trust and sovereignty. • In India, it is both official reserve and cultural wealth. • In China, it is accumulated strategically, with secrecy masking its scale. • At the IMF, it survives as a paradox — demonetized but indispensable.


Gold endures because it is nobody's liability, politically neutral, and symbolically powerful in ways fiat assets cannot replicate.





Section 22 — Gold Certificates, SDRs, and the Top of the Fed's Balance Sheet





22A-1 — Gold Certificates Before 1934: Origins and Circulation


Gold certificates were first authorized by Congress in the Act of March 3, 1863, with the first series issued in 1865. They were backed dollar-for-dollar by gold coin held in the Treasury, and could be exchanged on demand. Their purpose was to provide a paper substitute for heavy coin, especially for large transactions.


Initially, gold certificates circulated mainly among banks and merchants in wholesale and settlement use. Early denominations were large ($20 to $10,000), but by the late 19th century smaller denominations ($10, $20, $50) were also issued, making them more visible to the general public. Because each certificate represented specific coin held in Treasury vaults, they were widely regarded as among the most secure forms of paper money.


They were not legal tender in the narrow sense, but they were receivable for customs duties, taxes, and all public dues. Since customs payments were the main source of federal revenue in the 19th century, this provision ensured that gold certificates traded at par with gold coin. Many bankers and merchants actually preferred them to coin for convenience and security.


After the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1913, gold certificates were included among the reserve assets of Reserve Banks, helping them satisfy the statutory requirement to hold gold equal to 40% of Federal Reserve Notes in circulation. In this period, circulating gold certificates and gold coin were integral parts of the U.S. monetary base.





22A-2 — Transition to Book-Entry Certificates (1933–1934)


The Great Depression and banking crisis led to a dramatic change. In 1933, President Roosevelt's Executive Order 6102 required U.S. citizens and businesses to surrender most monetary gold (coins, bullion, and gold certificates) to the Treasury. Private ownership of monetary gold was prohibited.


The Gold Reserve Act of 1934 formalized this transformation. It: 1. Transferred ownership of all monetary gold from the Federal Reserve Banks to the U.S. Treasury. 2. Withdrew circulating gold certificates from public use. 3. Revalued gold from $20.67 to $35 per ounce, generating a revaluation gain of about $2 billion, which was used to fund the new Exchange Stabilization Fund (ESF). 4. Established non-circulating, book-entry gold certificates issued by the Treasury to the Federal Reserve Banks.


These new certificates were not redeemable in gold; they served only as an internal accounting mechanism. The Fed carried them on its balance sheet in place of gold itself. From that point forward, the "gold certificate account" became the first line on the Fed's balance sheet.





22B — The Gold Certificate Account Today


On the Federal Reserve's weekly H.4.1 balance sheet (Factors Affecting Reserve Balances of Depository Institutions), the first line under Assets is the Gold certificate account. In the release of August 27, 2025, this line totals $11,037 million. Immediately below it is the SDR certificate account ($15.2 billion), followed by Coin ($1.5 billion).


The gold certificate account represents Treasury-issued book-entry certificates backed by U.S. official gold reserves, but valued at the statutory $42.2222 per fine troy ounce (set in 31 U.S.C. §§ 5116–5117). At that valuation, Treasury's ~261.5 million ounces of gold are worth only ~$11 billion on the books, even though their market value is over $600 billion at 2025 prices.


Gold certificates also appear in Table 7 of the H.4.1, listed as part of the Collateral Held Against Federal Reserve Notes. Even though the 40% gold-backing requirement for notes was repealed in 1968 (Public Law 90-269), the certificates remain embedded in the legal and accounting framework.





22C — Treasury's Reporting and the U.S. Gold Stock


Treasury reports ~261,498,926 fine troy ounces (~8,133 tonnes) of gold in its Status Report of U.S. Treasury-Owned Gold Reserves. This stock is broken down by location: • Fort Knox, KY — ~4,583 tonnes • West Point, NY — ~1,682 tonnes • Denver, CO — ~1,364 tonnes • Federal Reserve Bank of New York (custody) — ~418 tonnes


All of this gold is carried at the statutory $42.22/oz, giving a total book value of ~$11 billion. Treasury records a liability for gold certificates issued to the Fed, making the two balance sheets match: the Fed shows them as an asset, Treasury shows them as a liability.





22D — The New York Fed's Vault (Custody, Not Ownership)


The New York Fed's gold vault at 33 Liberty Street, opened in 1924, is the largest known depository of official gold in the world. It lies ~80 feet below street level on Manhattan bedrock. • At its peak in 1973, it held over 12,000 tonnes, much of it transferred to the U.S. during and after World War II. • As of 2024, it holds about 507,000 bars (~6,331 tonnes). • The majority belongs to foreign central banks and international organizations (Bundesbank, IMF, Netherlands, Mexico, etc.). • Treasury stores only ~418 tonnes of its own gold there; most is at Fort Knox, West Point, and Denver. • All holdings are valued for accounting at $42.22/oz.


The NY Fed is a custodian only; it does not own the gold stored there.





22E — Special Drawing Rights (SDRs)


The SDR certificate account, which appears directly beneath gold on the Fed's H.4.1, reflects U.S. participation in the IMF's Special Drawing Rights system. Created in 1969, SDRs are reserve assets defined by a basket of major currencies (USD, EUR, CNY, JPY, GBP, weights last reset in 2022).


When the IMF allocates SDRs to the U.S., Treasury records them and issues SDR certificates to the Fed, just as with gold. These are carried as an asset by the Fed and appear second under assets, just below gold.





22F — Why Gold Still Comes First • Chronology: Gold certificates predate SDRs and have been on the Fed's balance sheet since 1934. • Law: Their valuation is locked in statute; they cannot be altered without Congress. • Symbolism: Gold still signals the Fed's historical foundations. • Continuity: The Fed has deliberately preserved this structure for over a century.


Section 23 — The Gold Revaluation Windfall and the Exchange Stabilization Fund (ESF)





23A — Background: Roosevelt's Gold Program


In the early 1930s, the U.S. was in the depths of the Great Depression. Banks failed in waves, prices collapsed, and citizens hoarded gold coin. In March 1933, President Roosevelt declared a nationwide banking holiday and then issued Executive Order 6102 (April 1933), which required U.S. citizens to surrender monetary gold to the Treasury.


Congress then passed the Gold Reserve Act of 1934 (48 Stat. 337). This law: 1. Transferred all gold from the Federal Reserve to the Treasury. 2. Withdrew circulating gold certificates from the public. 3. Ended domestic redemption of dollars into gold. 4. Revalued gold from $20.67/oz to $35/oz — a nearly 70% increase.





23B — The Revaluation "Windfall"


The U.S. held roughly 200 million troy ounces of gold in 1934. Raising the statutory price from $20.67 to $35/oz created an accounting profit of about $2 billion (1934 dollars).


Instead of being absorbed into the general budget, Congress earmarked this windfall to create a permanent fund for exchange-rate management.





23C — Creation of the ESF


Section 10 of the Gold Reserve Act established the Exchange Stabilization Fund (ESF) within the Treasury. Its features were unique: • Purpose: To stabilize the dollar's value in foreign exchange and to conduct interventions. • Funding: The ESF was capitalized entirely by the gold revaluation gain — no congressional appropriations. • Control: It was placed under the sole authority of the Treasury Secretary, subject only to presidential approval. • Flexibility: It could engage in gold and foreign-exchange transactions, and later in lending to foreign governments.


The ESF thus became a powerful, off-budget financial tool.





23D — Early Operations


In its first decades, the ESF: • Conducted interventions in foreign exchange markets to maintain the dollar's peg under the international gold standard. • Made stabilization loans, including support to Mexico (1936) and China (1930s–40s). • Coordinated with the Federal Reserve in managing exchange markets. • Played a behind-the-scenes role in the Bretton Woods negotiations (1944).





23E — Postwar Role • Under Bretton Woods (1945–1971), the ESF was used to defend the official $35/oz gold parity by buying and selling currencies. • After President Nixon suspended gold convertibility in 1971, the ESF shifted toward interventions in floating exchange markets. • By the late 20th century, it became central to U.S. responses to international financial crises.





23F — The 1995 Mexican Peso Crisis ("Tequila Crisis")


One of the most famous ESF episodes came in 1995, when Mexico faced a balance-of-payments crisis and a collapsing peso. Congress was reluctant to approve a bailout package, but the Treasury, using the ESF, arranged a $20 billion stabilization loan package for Mexico, alongside IMF support. • The ESF drew on its currency and SDR holdings to fund the package. • This intervention, coordinated with the IMF and the Bank for International Settlements, is widely credited with stabilizing Mexico's economy and averting contagion across Latin America. • The episode cemented the ESF's reputation as a powerful emergency backstop, able to act quickly without new congressional appropriations.





23G — Continuing Significance


The ESF has since been used in: • The Asian financial crisis (1997–98) to provide short-term liquidity support. • The 2008 financial crisis, where it guaranteed money-market mutual funds under Treasury's Temporary Guarantee Program. • Ongoing FX interventions in coordination with the Fed when deemed necessary.


Today, the ESF remains an unusual hybrid: a Depression-era creation, funded by a one-time gold revaluation, but still central to U.S. international financial policy.
 

Similar threads

DarkRange55
Replies
1
Views
25
Offtopic
Pluto
Pluto
DarkRange55
Replies
6
Views
190
Politics & Philosophy
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
Replies
6
Views
368
Offtopic
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
Replies
1
Views
233
Offtopic
bankai
bankai